Even as Americans have exercised some agency in choosing to live in suburbs, the whole system cannot truly be described as being the result of free market activity:
I get the concern and rarely disagree with Shelley, but there’s nothing free market about current single-family zoning rules. The suburban landscape largely is a creation of subsidies and zoning rules, which mandate only one house per certain size of lot and require umpteen parking spaces for every new shopping center, restaurant, office and church. Everything is micromanaged in the planning department.
I’m on the building committee of our church and have closely examined many proposed construction projects. It is so hard to build, expand or try any new development ideas because these planning edicts—designed mainly to protect our suburban way of life, and backed by residents trying to bolster their property values—are costly and inflexible…
But the underlying debate is about two visions of our California landscape. One side wants to protect our suburban model and the other side wants to urbanize. It’s a false choice driven by their own personal preferences. We need more apartments and condos. We need more single-family neighborhoods. We need to allow builders to provide the housing products people want, and different people want different things. The same people want different things at different stages of their lives. I live on an acreage, but now that we’re empty nesters, my wife and I plan to move into the city. That’s why I’m squarely on neither side.
After my housing column last week, I’ve heard from readers who oppose the legislation. Frankly, I’m frustrated by some of their arguments. To summarize some comments: If you can’t afford to live around here, then maybe move someplace else. There are too many people here already and too much traffic congestion. If your kids can’t afford California, they should consider less-costly states. Such views transcend political affiliation.
Zoning is a good example of how regulations can dictate what communities can construct and then who can reside or work in such locations.
Add two other other less-than-free-market aspects of suburbia:
1. A legacy of racial and class discrimination in suburbs.
2. Government subsidies for highways and other local services as well as propping up suburban housing in the form of single-family homes.
Americans might not acknowledge the ways suburbs developed and may even resist seeing them as social products. But, addressing tough suburban issues such as affordable housing probably requires thinking and acting at more collective levels than letting the beloved local governments dictate what they want (which can often deliberately lead to exclusion).
Pingback: “To urbanists, suburbia is self-evidently evil” | Legally Sociable
Pingback: Housing as the ultimate marker of poorly functioning (free) markets | Legally Sociable
Pingback: Which 2020 candidate will set themselves apart by promoting homeownership? | Legally Sociable
Pingback: Six Democrat candidates push new housing policies and it does not register at the latest debates | Legally Sociable
Pingback: Trump administration pushes housing deregulation | Legally Sociable
Pingback: Reminder: “Americans have no comparable safety net for housing” | Legally Sociable
Pingback: Presenting suburban growth and the role of race differently in high school textbooks | Legally Sociable
Pingback: Housing appraisals reflect existing racial inequalities in housing | Legally Sociable